Should Equity Be a Goal of Economic Policy?
IMF Fiscal Affairs Department
Over the past decade, global output has grown by more than 3 percent a year and
inflation has slowed in most regions. The fruits of this growth have not been shared
equally, however, and income disparities have grown in many countries, developed as well
as developing. One of the most pressing issues facing policymakers today is how to respond
to these trends. To what extent are growth and equity complementary, and to what extent is
there a trade-off between the two?
Why Is Equity Important?
The answers to these questions depend on how equity is defined. Different societies
have different perceptions of what is equitable, and these social and cultural norms shape
the policies they will adopt to promote equity. Although there is a consensus that extreme
inequality of income, wealth, or opportunity is unfair and that efforts should be made to
raise the incomes of the poorest members of society, there is little agreement on the
desirability of greater income equality for its own sake or on what constitutes a fair
distribution of income. Equity issues are especially knotty because they are inextricably
intertwined with social values. Nonetheless, economic policymakers are devoting greater
attention to them for a number of reasons:
 | Some societies view equity as a worthy goal in and of itself because of its moral
implications and its intimate link with fairness and social justice. |
 | Policies that promote equity can help, directly and indirectly, to reduce poverty. When
incomes are more evenly distributed, fewer individuals fall below the poverty line.
Equity-enhancing policies, particularly such investment in human capital as education,
can, in the long run, boost economic growth, which, in turn, has been shown to alleviate
poverty. |
 | Heightened awareness of the discrimination suffered by certain groups because of their
gender, race, or ethnic origin has focused attention on the need to ensure that these
groups have adequate access to government services and receive fair treatment in the labor
market. |
 | Many of today's policies will affect the welfare of future generations, which raises the
issue of intergenerational equity. For instance, the provision of very generous pension
benefits to today's retirees could be at the expense of tomorrow's retirees--an important
issue in many transition and industrial countries. |
 | Policies that promote equity can boost social cohesion and reduce political conflict. To
be effective, most policies require broad political support, which is more likely to be
forthcoming when the distribution of income is seen as fair. However, macroeconomic
adjustment that entails growth-enhancing structural reforms such as privatization may
increase unemployment and worsen inequality in the short run. In such circumstances,
well-targeted social safety nets to shelter the consumption levels of the poor are
critically important. |
Growing Inequality
Income inequality varies greatly from region to region. It is greatest in Latin America
and sub-Saharan Africa, and lowest in Eastern Europe; other regions fall between these two
extremes. In Latin America, the average "Gini coefficient"--the most commonly
used measure of inequality, with 0 representing perfect equality and 1 representing total
inequality--is nearly 0.5. The average Gini coefficient in sub-Saharan Africa is slightly
lower, but there is considerable variation among countries. Income inequality has a
regional dimension in both Africa and Latin America--average incomes are significantly
higher in urban areas than in rural areas.
In recent years, income inequality has been increasing in a large number of countries.
This increase has been most striking in the economies in transition to market-oriented
systems, where the average Gini coefficient had been about 0.25 until the late 1980s; by
the mid-1990s, it had risen to more than 0.30. Although this may not appear to be a large
increase, it is quite significant for such a short period of time, since Gini coefficients
tend to be relatively stable in countries over long periods. In the past decade, income
inequality has also increased in several Group of Seven countries (for example, Germany,
Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States) and is beginning to rise in some East
Asian countries (China and Thailand).
Much of the debate about income distribution has centered on wage earnings. But wages
tell only part of the story. The distribution of wealth (and, by implication, capital
income) is more concentrated than labor income. In Africa and Latin America, unequal
ownership of land has been identified as an important factor in the overall distribution
of income. Furthermore, in recent years, there has been a shift from labor to capital
income (including from self-employment) in many countries. In transition economies, this
shift has been due primarily to the privatization of state-owned assets. The analysis of
trends in nonlabor income in countries with well-developed capital markets and pension
funds is more complicated. Pension funds and other financial institutions receive a
sizable portion of capital income, and the share of capital income in total household
income typically changes over the life cycle of the individuals in the household.
Is Globalization to Blame?
Globalization has linked the labor, product, and capital markets of economies around
the world. Increased trade, capital and labor movements, and technological progress have
led to greater specialization in production and the dispersion of specialized production
processes to geographically distant locations. Developing countries, with their abundant
supply of unskilled labor, have a comparative advantage relative to developed countries in
the production of unskilled-labor-intensive goods and services. As a result, production of
these goods in developed countries has come under increased competitive pressure. Economic
theory tells us this should apply downward pressure on the relative compensation of
unskilled workers in developed countries and upward pressure on the compensation of their
counterparts in developing countries.
On the basis of this theory, some have claimed that globalization is to blame for
growing income inequality in developed countries. Others argue that the widening gap
between the wages of skilled workers and unskilled workers in the industrial countries is
due to the development and dispersion of skill-intensive technologies rather than to
increased trade. Several empirical studies have tried to gauge the relative importance of
trade versus technological progress for the decline in wages of unskilled workers in
developed countries. Estimates of the contribution of increased trade to the total
increase of the wage differential between unskilled and skilled workers range from
negligible to 50 percent. This large variation reflects the structure of production in
developed countries and the share of the labor market that is in direct competition with
low-skilled workers in developing countries.
The debate regarding the effect of globalization on income distribution in developing
countries mirrors the debate on developed countries. Although, all other things being
equal, increased openness would be expected to boost the relative wage of unskilled
workers in developing countries, experience has been mixed. Evidence suggests that the
relative wages of unskilled workers rose in East Asian countries in the 1960s and 1970s
but fell in Latin America in the 1980s and early 1990s. There are two possible
explanations for why wages fell in Latin America: first, the opening up of developing
Asian countries--Bangladesh, India, China, Indonesia, and Pakistan--where unskilled labor
is even more abundant; second, the availability of new production technologies that are
biased toward skilled labor.
Globalization's effect on income distribution appears to be determined to some extent
by a country's level of development and the technologies available to it. Similarly,
exposure to international competition may change institutions (for example, trade unions),
and thereby affect income distribution. Some observers contend that, because of the
mobility of capital, globalization limits the ability of union workers to achieve a
"union wage premium," decreasing the bargaining power of workers vis-à-vis
capital. In addition, globalization may lead to sharp short-run changes in the
distribution of income, as barriers to trade are reduced and the distribution of
production is reallocated among sectors.
Many argue that globalization makes it more difficult for governments to carry out
equitable policies. Increasingly mobile capital and labor have limited the ability of
governments to levy taxes and transfer them to those affected by globalization. To the
extent that capital is more mobile than labor, the incidence of taxes to finance safety
nets for those affected by globalization is shifted to labor.
Policy Responses
How much countries have focused on promoting equity, and the strategies they have
adopted, vary widely. Some countries have actively promoted the use of public resources to
improve the situation of the bottom tier of the income distribution. Others have focused
on the top percentiles with highly progressive taxes. Yet others--concerned that policies
targeting the poor may result in economic inefficiencies and distortions that retard
growth--have taken an indirect approach, seeking to help low-income families by
stimulating overall economic growth.
In Latin America during the 1980s, policymakers' primary goal was achieving sustainable
growth, and a viable balance of payments and structural reforms were seen as critical to
achieving this goal. Growth has also been one of the primary goals of the transition
economies, but the strategy in these countries has included policies aimed at helping
groups likely to be hurt by the transition. Such policies have included distributing
shares of privatized enterprises, adapting social policy instruments to protect vulnerable
groups, and erecting social safety nets (for example, targeted subsidies, cash
compensation in lieu of subsidies, severance pay and retraining for retrenched public
sector employees, and public works programs). However, the lack of budgetary resources has
hampered implementation of these policies.
Fiscal policy--taxation and spending--is a government's most direct tool for
redistributing income, in both the short and the long run. Nevertheless, the effect of
redistributive tax policies, especially in the face of globalization, has been small. It
is widely accepted that policymakers should focus on developing a broadly based,
efficient, and easily administered tax system with moderate marginal rates. An important
subsidiary issue is how to distribute the burden of taxation so the system is seen as fair
and just. Achieving these various goals is naturally complex and politically sensitive.
The expenditure side of the budget has offered better opportunities than the tax side
for redistributing income. The link between income distribution and social
spending--especially spending on health and education, through which governments can
influence the formation and distribution of human capital--is particularly strong, and
public investment in human capital can be an efficient way to reduce income inequality
over the long run.
The resources governments can and should devote to social expenditures depends on
various factors, including the tax-to-GDP ratio and the resources devoted to other
spending. Theory tells us public expenditure should displace private expenditure only when
it yields higher social benefits. Priority should be given to the most productive public
expenditures, and unproductive public expenditures--for example, excessive military
spending, wages for an overstaffed civil service, and budgetary transfers to inefficient
public enterprises--should be curtailed. And evidence suggests that civil service reform
and the privatization of services that can be better provided by the private
sector--especially if accompanied by a reallocation of expenditures to the social
sectors--are likely to be both growth- and equity-enhancing, particularly in developing
countries, where public sector employees come primarily from the middle- and
upper-middle-income classes.
Outlays on health and education can improve the existing pattern of income
distribution, depending to a large extent on the allocation of expenditures on various
economic sectors. Studies show that spending on basic health care and primary education is
far more effective in reaching the poor than spending on higher education or
hospital-based curative care; it reduces disparities in human capital across income groups
and can narrow income inequality in the long run. Studies also show that, in countries
without some form of pooling of health risks, serious illnesses are the single most
important factor driving families into poverty.
Although many view fiscal policy as the principal vehicle for assisting low-income
groups and those affected adversely in the short run by reform programs, a number of
countries have introduced labor market policies to influence income distribution--the
rationale being that relative wages exert a strong influence on overall income inequality.
Many European countries have opted for high minimum wages, generous unemployment benefits,
and a wide range of job-protection measures. Although these policies can result in labor
market rigidities, advocates maintain that they help achieve a socially desirable
redistribution of income; opponents argue that they discourage new investment and dampen
job creation and growth. The United States, with its alternative approach to labor market
flexibility, has achieved high employment levels, but the cost may be larger inequalities.
To mitigate any potentially adverse effects of market flexibility on low-wage workers, the
United States has introduced wage subsidies that simultaneously redistribute income and
promote employment. Given the potentially large impact of labor market policies on
earnings, these competing visions of the labor market are central to the debate over
income inequality in many developing and newly industrialized countries.
Governments can also indirectly affect income levels and distribution through monetary
policy and the overall stance of macroeconomic policy. For example, high inflation tends
to curtail economic growth and widen income inequality. Trade liberalization--especially
when it occurs in developing countries that have had such restrictive trade policies as
taxation of agricultural exports and protective tariffs against imports--may boost
economic growth and lead to more equitable conditions. Currency devaluations may also have
implications for equity, particularly in low-income countries, where the poor are often
concentrated in the agriculture-intensive export sector and middle- and upper-income urban
dwellers tend to be more dependent on imports.
Also important is whether governments should focus on outcomes--such as decreasing the
number of people living in poverty--or on ensuring that all members of society have equal
opportunities. In extreme cases of income inequality, outcomes are clearly critical. In
other cases, setting up a level playing field may be all that is necessary, and greater
emphasis can be placed on policies that facilitate mobility between income classes, and on
ensuring that income and wealth are acquired justly and fairly. To promote equality of
opportunity, governments can adopt such measures as deregulating the economy, setting up
strong and accountable institutions and a well-functioning judicial system, reducing
opportunities for corrupt practices (curbing corruption can directly reduce income
inequality, as the gains from corrupt practices tend to be captured by the well-to-do),
and providing adequate access to health and education services.
Obstacles to Overcome
Governments seeking to carry out equity-oriented policies face a number of obstacles:
 | First and foremost is the financing required: high levels of spending on targeted
programs may not be consistent with a sustainable macroeconomic framework. |
 | Governments in many developing countries, where a large share of the population is
engaged in rural and informal sector activities, may be unable to reach the most
vulnerable groups. The rural and informal sectors may have limited interaction with formal
sector institutions, including the government, complicating the delivery of government
assistance (for example, cash transfers). |
 | Similarly, a lack of administrative capacity may hamper redistributive efforts. For
example, tax evasion is a severe problem in countries with weak tax administration, making
it difficult for governments to use the tax system as a vehicle to finance redistributive
policies. |
 | Political constraints--low-income groups typically have less political power than other
interest groups--may impede efforts to reallocate spending toward the poor or redistribute
land or other assets. |
 | Legal impediments may also prevent governments from taking measures to promote
equity--for example, constitutional rules on revenue sharing may limit the amount of
resources a central government can allocate to redistributive policies. |
Summary
Despite widespread economic expansion, income gaps have widened during the past decade
in many parts of the world, including in the industrial countries. This trend has
heightened concerns about the treatment of equity in the formulation of economic policy.
Equity and growth can be complementary: some policies that promote equity--particularly
investment in human capital--can boost growth in the long run and thus alleviate extreme
poverty, increase social cohesion, and reduce the scope for political conflict. Policy
choices are not always so easy, however: when growth and equity do not go hand in hand,
when and how should governments intervene?
The strategies that countries have adopted vary widely. The most effective tool for
redistributing income is fiscal policy. And of the two sides of the budget--taxation and
spending--the expenditure side, especially spending on health and education, has offered
the better opportunities for reducing income inequality over the long term. But
governments have also pursued income redistribution through labor market measures,
monetary policy, and the overall stance of macroeconomic policy.
An important question is whether governments should focus on outcomes (such as
decreasing broad measures of income inequality) or on ensuring that all members of society
have equal opportunities (for example, through policies that facilitate mobility among
income classes and by setting up a well-functioning judicial system and reducing the scope
for corruption). In all these efforts, governments face difficult obstacles: lack of
financial resources, difficult-to-reach target groups, weak administrative capacity, and
legal and political constraints. A consensus is forming nevertheless that governments
should sometimes intervene to ensure not only that the size of the pie increases, but that
everybody gets a fair share.

|